×

Environmental disasters as risk regulation catalysts? The role of Bhopal, Chernobyl, Exxon Valdez, Love Canal, and Three Mile Island in shaping U.S. environmental law. (English) Zbl 1151.91572

Summary: Unexpected events such as environmental catastrophes capture wide public attention. Soon after five major shocks the Three Mile Island, Love Canal, Bhopal, Chernobyl, and the Exxon Valdez oil spill-Congress voted on new risk regulations. This paper conducts an event study to test whether individual congressional representatives were “shocked” by these environmental disasters into increasing their probability of voting in favor of risk legislation. On average, representatives were less likely to vote in favor of bills tied to these five events. Significant heterogeneity in representatives’ responses to these shocks is documented. Liberal Northeast representatives were most likely to increase their pro-environment voting in the aftermath of these shocks.

MSC:

91B30 Risk theory, insurance (MSC2010)
91B76 Environmental economics (natural resource models, harvesting, pollution, etc.)

Software:

Greenstone
PDFBibTeX XMLCite
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Baldwin, Robert and Christopher Magee. (2000). ”Is Trade Policy for Sale? Congressional Voting on Recent Trade Bills,” Public Choice 105(1/2), 79–101.
[2] Besley, Timothy and Robin Burgess. (2002). ”The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness. Theory and Evidence From India,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 1415–1452. · Zbl 1032.91726
[3] Bonardi, Jean-Philippe and Gerald Keim. (2005). ”Corporate Political Strategies for Widely Salient Issues,” Academy of Management Review 30(3), 555–576.
[4] Bui, Linda and Christopher Mayer. (2003). ”Regulation and Capitalization of Environmental Amenities: Evidence from the Toxic Release Inventory in Massachusetts,” Review of Economics and Statistics 85(3), 693–708.
[5] DellaVigna, Stefano and Ethan Kaplan. (2006). ”The Fox News Effect: Media Bias and Voting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(3).
[6] Dower, Roger. (1990). ”Hazardous Waste.” In Paul Portney (ed.), Public Policies for Environmental Protection. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC.
[7] Ehrlich, Issac and Gary Becker. (1972). ”Market Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Protection,” Journal of Political Economy 80(4), 623–648.
[8] Eisensee, Thomas and David Stromberg. (2007). ”News Droughts, News Floods, and U.S. Disaster Relief,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(2).
[9] Epple, Dennis and Michael Visscher. (1984). ”Environmental Pollution: Modeling, Occurrence, Detection and Deterrence,” Journal of Law and Economics 27, 29–60.
[10] Fischer, Michael. (1996). ”Union Carbide’s Bhopal Incident: A Retrospective,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 12(2/3), 257–269.
[11] Fredriksson, Per, Eric Neumayer, Richard Damania, and Scott Gates. (2005). ”Environmentalism, Democracy and Pollution Control,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 49(2), 343–365. · Zbl 1112.91355
[12] Gentzkow, Matthew and Jesse Shapiro. (2006). ”Media Bias and Reputation,” Journal of Political Economy 114, 280–316.
[13] Gershtenson, Joseph, Brian Smith, and William Mangun. (2006). ”Friends of the Earth? Partisanship, Party Control of Congress, and Environmental Legislation in Congress,” Politics & Policy 34(1), 66–92.
[14] Greenstone, Michael and Justin Gallagher. (2005). ”Does Hazardous Waste Matter? Evidence from the Housing Market and the Superfund Program,” NBER Working Paper 11790.
[15] Grossman, Gene and Alan Krueger. (1995). ”Economic Growth and the Environment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(2), 353–377. · Zbl 0831.90040
[16] Hamilton, James. (1997). ”Taxes, Torts and the Toxic Release Inventory: Congressional Voting on Instruments to Control Pollution,” Economic Inquiry 35(4), 745–763.
[17] Hamilton, James. (2004). All the News That’s Fit to Sell. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
[18] Hamilton, James. (2005). Regulation Through Revelation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[19] Hird, John A. (1993). ”Congressional Voting on Superfund: Self-Interest or Ideology?” Public Choice 77, 333–357.
[20] Hird, John A. (1994). Superfund: The Political Economy of Environmental Risk. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.
[21] Kane, Edward. (1996). ”De Jure Interstate Banking: Why Only Now?” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 28, 141–161.
[22] Karpoff, Jonathan, John Lott, and Eric Wehrly. (2005). ”The Reputational Penalties for Environmental Violations: Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Law and Economics 48, 653–674.
[23] Keohane, Nathaniel, Richard Revesz, and Robert Stavins. (1998). ”The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy,” Harvard Economic Law Review 22, 313–367.
[24] Krupnikov, Yanna, Adam Seth Levine, Arthur Lupia and Markus Prior. (2006). ”Public Ignorance and Estate Tax Repeal: The Effect of Partisan Differences and Survey Incentives,” National Tax Journal 59(3), 425–438.
[25] Kuran, Timur and Cass R. Sunstein. (1999). ”Availability Cascades and Risk Regulation,” Stanford Law Review 51(4), 683–768.
[26] Kurtz, Rick S. (2004). ”Coastal Oil Pollution: Spills, Crisis and Policy Change,” Review of Policy Research 21(2), 199–217.
[27] Lazarus, Richard J. (2004). The Making of Environmental Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
[28] Lyon, Thomas and John Maxwell. (2004). Corporate Environmentalism and Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[29] Mullainathan, Sendhil and Andrei Shleifer. (2005). ”The Market for News,” American Economic Review 95(4), 1031–1053.
[30] Nelson, Jon P. (2002). ”Green Voting and Ideology: LCV Scores and Roll-Call Voting in the U.S. Senate, 1988–98,” Review of Economics and Statistics 84(3), 518–529.
[31] Noll, Roger and James Krier. (1990). ”Some Implications of Cognitive Psychology for Risk Regulation,” The Journal of Legal Studies 19(2), 747–779.
[32] Pashigian, Peter B. (1985). ”Environmental Regulation: Whose Self-interests are Being Protected?” Economic Inquiry 23(4), 551–584.
[33] Peltzman, Sam. (1984). ”Constituent Interest and Congressional Voting,” Journal of Law and Economics 27(1), 181–210.
[34] Peltzman, Sam. (1999). ”The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1–59.
[35] Poole, Keith and Howard Rosenthal. (1997). Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.
[36] Rabin, Matthew. (2002). ”Inference by Believers in the Law of Small Numbers,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 775–816. · Zbl 1021.91051
[37] Rosa, Eugene and Riley Dunlap. (1994). ”Poll Trends: Nuclear Power: Three Decades of Public Opinion,” Public Opinion Quarterly 58(2), 295–324.
[38] Seldon, Thomas and Daqing Song. (1995). ”Neoclassical Growth, the J Curve for Abatement and the Inverted U Curve for Pollution,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29(2), 162–168. · Zbl 0858.90037
[39] Sigman, Hilary. (2001). ”The Pace of Progress at Superfund Sites: Policy Goals and Interest Group Influence,” Journal of Law and Economics 44(1), 315–344.
[40] Sunstein, Cass. (2003). ”Terrorism and Probability Neglect,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 26(2/3), 121–136. · Zbl 1047.91525
[41] Viscusi, W. Kip. and James T. Hamilton. (1999). ”Are Risk Regulators Rational? Evidence from Hazardous Waste Cleanup Decisions,” American Economic Review 89(4), 1010–1027.
[42] Viscusi, W. Kip. and Richard J. Zeckhauser. (2006). ”National Survey Evidence on Disasters and Relief: Risk Beliefs, Self-Interest, and Compassion,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 33(1/2), 13–36. · Zbl 1130.91358
[43] Zeckhauser, Richard J. (1996). ”The Economics of Catastrophes,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 12(2/3), 113–140.
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.