×

Reference points and negative reciprocity in simple sequential games. (English) Zbl 1037.91505

Summary: We investigate experimentally whether preferences over an outcome depend on what other possible outcomes of the situation under consideration are, i.e., whether choices are “menu dependent.” In simple sequential games we analyze whether reactions to a certain benchmark outcome are influenced by changes in the payoffs of another outcome, not attainable at that time, called the “reference point.” Our data provide evidence that is favorable to the notion of menu dependence. Alterations of the reference point can lead to quantitatively significant changes in behavior at the benchmark outcome. The behavior we observe can be interpreted in terms of negative reciprocity.

MSC:

91A20 Multistage and repeated games
91A90 Experimental studies
PDF BibTeX XML Cite
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] Abbink, K, Bolton, G. E, Sadrieh, A, and, Tang, F.-F. 1996, Adaptative Learning versus Punishment in Ultimatum Bargaining, mimeo. · Zbl 0989.91505
[2] Bolton, G.E.; Brandts, J.; Ockenfels, A., Measuring motivations for the reciprocal responses observed in a simple dilemma game, Experimental econ., 1, 207-219, (1998) · Zbl 0941.91500
[3] Bolton, G.E.; Zwick, R., Anonymity versus punishment in ultimatum bargaining, Games econ. behav., 10, 95-121, (1995) · Zbl 0831.90137
[4] Bolton, G.E.; Ockenfels, A., ERC, A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition, Amer. econ. rev., 90, 166-193, (2000)
[5] Blount, S., When social outcomes aren’t fair: the effect of causal attributions on preferences, Organizational behav. human decision processes, 63, 131-144, (1995)
[6] Camerer, C.; Thaler, R.H., Anomalies: ultimatums, dictators and manners, J. econ. perspect., 9, 209-219, (1995)
[7] Charness, G. 1997, Attribution and Reciprocity in a Simulated Labor Market: An Experimental Investigation, mimeo, Department of Economics, U.C. Berkeley, March.
[8] Fehr, E.; Schmidt, K.M., A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation, Quart. J. econ., 114, 817-868, (1999) · Zbl 0944.91022
[9] Forsythe, R.; Horowitz, J.L.; Savin, N.E.; Sefton, M., Fairness in simple bargaining experiments, Games econ. behav., 6, 347-369, (1994) · Zbl 0804.90146
[10] Gale, J.; Binmore, K.G.; Samuelson, L., Learning to be imperfect: the ultimatum game, Games econ. behav., 8, 56-90, (1995) · Zbl 0827.90146
[11] Güth, W.; Tietz, R., Ultimatum bargaining behavior: A survey and comparison of experimental results, J. econ. psych., 11, 417-449, (1990)
[12] Harrison, G.W.; Hirshleifer, J., An experimental evaluation of weakest link/best shot model of public goods, J. polit. economy, 97, 201-225, (1989)
[13] Kagel, J.H.; Kim, C.; Moser, D., Fairness in ultimatum games with asymmetric information and asymmetric payoffs, Games econ. behav., 13, 100-110, (1996) · Zbl 0848.90141
[14] Prasnikar, V.; Roth, A.E., Considerations of fairness and strategy: experimental data from sequential games, Quart J. econ., 107, 865-888, (1992) · Zbl 0825.90814
[15] Rabin, M., Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics, Amer. econ. rev., 83, 1281-1302, (1993)
[16] Sen, A., Maximization and the act of choice, Econometrica, 65, 745-779, (1997) · Zbl 0891.90013
[17] Siegel, S.; Castellan, J., Nonparametric statistics for the behavioral sciences, (1988), McGraw-Hill New York
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. It attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming the completeness or perfect precision of the matching.