×

Intermediaries in trust: indirect reciprocity, incentives, and norms. (English) Zbl 1435.91049

Summary: Any trust situation involves a certain amount of risk for trustors that trustees could abuse. In some cases, intermediaries exist who play a crucial role in the exchange by providing reputational information. To examine under what conditions intermediary opinion could have a positive impact on cooperation, we designed two experiments based on a modified version of the investment game where intermediaries rated the behaviour of trustees under various incentive schemes and different role structures. We found that intermediaries can increase trust if there is room for indirect reciprocity between the involved parties. We also found that the effect of monetary incentives and social norms cannot be clearly separable in these situations. If properly designed, monetary incentives for intermediaries can have a positive effect. On the one hand, when intermediary rewards are aligned with the trustor’s interest, investments and returns tend to increase. On the other hand, fixed monetary incentives perform less than any other incentive schemes and endogenous social norms in ensuring trust and fairness. These findings should make us reconsider the mantra of incentivization of social and public conventional policy.

MSC:

91A90 Experimental studies

Software:

R; Z-Tree

References:

[1] Coleman, J. S., Foundations of Social Theory (1990), Harvard, Mass, USA: Harvard University Press, Harvard, Mass, USA
[2] Burt, R. S.; Knez, M., Kinds of third-party effects on trust, Rationality and Society, 7, 3, 255-292 (1995)
[3] Cookm, K. S.; Hardin, R.; Hechter, M.; Opp, K.-D., Norms of cooperativeness and networks of trust, Social Norms, 327-347 (2001), New York, NY, USA: Russel Sage Foundation, New York, NY, USA
[4] Bateson, M.; Nettle, D.; Roberts, G., Cues of being watched enhance cooperation in a real-world setting, Biology Letters, 2, 3, 412-414 (2006) · doi:10.1098/rsbl.2006.0509
[5] Bohnet, I.; Frey, B. S., The sound of silence in prisoner’s dilemma and dictator games, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 38, 1, 43-57 (1999) · doi:10.1016/S0167-2681(98)00121-8
[6] Cason, T. N.; Mui, V.-L., A laboratory study of group polarisation in the team dictator game, Economic Journal, 107, 444, 1465-1483 (1997) · doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.1997.tb00058.x
[7] Haley, K. J.; Fessler, D. M. T., Nobody’s watching? Subtle cues affect generosity an anonymous economic game, Evolution and Human Behavior, 26, 3, 245-256 (2005) · doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2005.01.002
[8] Rigdon, M.; Ishii, K.; Watabe, M.; Kitayama, S., Minimal social cues in the dictator game, Journal of Economic Psychology, 30, 3, 358-367 (2009) · doi:10.1016/j.joep.2009.02.002
[9] Boero, R.; Bravo, G.; Castellani, M.; Squazzoni, F., Reputational cues in repeated trust games, Journal of Socio-Economics, 38, 6, 871-877 (2009) · doi:10.1016/j.socec.2009.05.004
[10] Bacharach, M.; Gambetta, D.; Cook, K. S., Trust in signs, Trust and Society, 2, 148-184 (2001), New York, NY, USA: Russell Sage, New York, NY, USA
[11] Squazzoni, F.; Bravo, G.; Takács, K., Does incentive provision increase the quality of peer review? An experimental study, Research Policy, 42, 1, 287-294 (2013) · doi:10.1016/j.respol.2012.04.014
[12] Cook, K.; Hardin, R.; Levi, M., Cooperation without Trust (2005), New York, NY, USA: Russell Sage, New York, NY, USA
[13] Hardin, R., Trust and Trustworthiness (2004), New York, NY, USA: Russell Sage, New York, NY, USA
[14] Bailey, J. P.; Bakos, Y., An exploratory study of the emerging role of electronic intermediaries, International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 1, 3, 7-20 (1997)
[15] Palmer, J. W.; Bailey, J. P.; Faraj, S., The role of intermediaries in the development of trust on the WWW: the use and prominence of trusted third parties and privacy statements, Journal of Computer-Mediated Communication, 5, 3 (2000)
[16] Sorenson, O.; Stuart, T. E., Syndication networks and the spatial distribution of venture capital investments, American Journal of Sociology, 106, 6, 1546-1588 (2001) · doi:10.1086/321301
[17] Berg, J.; Dickhaut, J.; McCabe, K., Trust, reciprocity and social history, Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 1, 122-142 (1995) · Zbl 0831.90008 · doi:10.1006/game.1995.1027
[18] Johnson, N. D.; Mislin, A. A., Trust games: a meta-analysis, Journal of Economic Psychology, 32, 5, 865-889 (2011) · doi:10.1016/j.joep.2011.05.007
[19] Buskens, V.; Raub, W.; Wittek, R.; Snijders, T. A. B.; Nee, V., Rational choice research on social dilemmas: embeddedness effects on trust, Handbook of Rational Choice Social Research (2008), New York, NY, USA: Russell Sage, New York, NY, USA
[20] Buskens, V.; Raub, W.; van der Veer, J., Trust in triads: an experimental study, Social Networks, 32, 4, 301-312 (2010) · doi:10.1016/j.socnet.2010.05.001
[21] Fehr, E.; Fischbacher, U., The nature of human altruism, Nature, 425, 6960, 785-791 (2003) · doi:10.1038/nature02043
[22] Keser, C., Experimental games for the design of reputation management systems, IBM Systems Journal, 42, 3, 498-506 (2003) · doi:10.1147/sj.423.0498
[23] Seinen, I.; Schram, A., Social status and group norms: indirect reciprocity in a repeated helping experiment, European Economic Review, 50, 3, 581-602 (2006) · doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2004.10.005
[24] Barrera, D.; Van De Bunt, G. G., Learning to trust: networks effects through time, European Sociological Review, 25, 6, 709-721 (2009) · doi:10.1093/esr/jcn078
[25] Frey, B. S.; Oberholzer-Gee, F., The cost of price incentives: an empirical analysis of motivation crowding- out, American Economic Review, 87, 4, 746-755 (1997)
[26] Alexander, R. D., The Biology of Moral Systems (1987), New York, NY, USA: Basic Books, New York, NY, USA
[27] Nowak, M. A.; Sigmund, K., The dynamics of indirect reciprocity, Journal of Theoretical Biology, 194, 4, 561-574 (1998) · doi:10.1006/jtbi.1998.0775
[28] Laffont, J.-J.; Martimort, D., The Theory of Incentives: The Principal-Agent Model (2002), Princeton, NJ, USA: Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, USA
[29] Ariely, D.; Bracha, A.; Meier, S., Doing good or doing well? Image motivation and monetary incentives in behaving prosocially, American Economic Review, 99, 1, 544-555 (2009) · doi:10.1257/aer.99.1.544
[30] Heyman, J.; Ariely, D., Effort for payment: a tale of two markets, Psychological Science, 15, 11, 787-793 (2004) · doi:10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00757.x
[31] R Core Team, R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing (2012), Vienna, Austria: R Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna, Austria
[32] Kollock, P., Social dilemmas: the anatomy of cooperation, Annual Review of Sociology, 24, 182-214 (1998)
[33] Almås, I.; Cappelen, A. W.; Sørensen, E. Ø.; Tungodden, B., Fairness and the development of inequality acceptance, Science, 328, 5982, 1176-1178 (2010) · doi:10.1126/science.1187300
[34] Fehr, E.; Schmidt, K. M., A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 3, 817-868 (1999) · Zbl 0944.91022 · doi:10.1162/003355399556151
[35] Nowak, M. A.; Page, K. M.; Sigmund, K., Fairness versus reason in the ultimatum game, Science, 289, 5485, 1773-1775 (2000) · doi:10.1126/science.289.5485.1773
[36] Rabin, M., Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics, American Economic Review, 83, 1281-1302 (1993)
[37] Cochard, F.; Nguyen Van, P.; Willinger, M., Trusting behavior in a repeated investment game, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 55, 1, 31-44 (2004) · doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2003.07.004
[38] Bowles, S., Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine “the moral sentiments”: evidence from economic experiments, Science, 320, 5883, 1605-1609 (2008) · doi:10.1126/science.1152110
[39] Boero, R.; Bravo, G.; Castellani, M.; Squazzoni, F., Why bother with what others tell you? An experimental data-driven agent-based model, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 13, 3, article 6 (2010)
[40] Nowak, M. A.; Highfield, R., SuperCooperators: Altruism, Evolution, and Why We Need Each Other to Succeed (2011), New York, NY, USA: Free Press, New York, NY, USA
[41] Frey, B. S.; Jegen, R., Motivation crowding theory, Journal of Economic Surveys, 15, 5, 589-611 (2001) · doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00150
[42] Squazzoni, F., A social science-inspired complexity policy: beyond the mantra of incentivization, Complexity, 19, 5-13 (2014) · doi:10.1002/cplx.21520
[43] Shafir, E., The Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy (2013), Princeton, NJ, USA: Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, USA
[44] Bowles, S.; Polanía-Reyes, S., Economic incentives and social preferences: substitutes or complements?, Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 2, 368-425 (2012) · doi:10.1257/jel.50.2.368
[45] Greiner, B.; Kremer, K.; Macho, V., An online recruitment system for economic experiments, Forschung und Wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003, 79-93 (2004), Göttingen, Germany: Gesellschaft für wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung, Göttingen, Germany
[46] Fischbacher, U., Z-Tree: zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments, Experimental Economics, 10, 2, 171-178 (2007) · doi:10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.