×

Should commodity investors follow commodities’ prices? (English) Zbl 1417.91451

Summary: Most institutional investors gain access to commodities through diversified index funds, even though mean-reverting prices and low correlation among commodities’ returns suggest that two-fund separation does not hold for commodities. In contrast to demand for stocks and bonds, we find that, on average, demand for commodities is largely insensitive to risk aversion, with intertemporal hedging demand playing a major role for more risk averse investors. Comparing the optimal strategies of investors who observe only the index to those of investors who observe all commodities, we find that information on commodity prices leads to significant welfare gains, even if trading is confined to the index only.

MSC:

91G10 Portfolio theory
PDF BibTeX XML Cite
Full Text: DOI

References:

[1] H. Abou-Kandil, G. Freiling, V. Ionescu, and G. Jank, Matrix Riccati Equations in Control and Systems Theory, Birkhäuser, Basel, 2003. · Zbl 1027.93001
[2] J. Amendinger, P. Imkeller, and M. Schweizer, Additional logarithmic utility of an insider, Stochastic Process. Appl., 75 (1998), pp. 263–286. · Zbl 0934.91020
[3] S. Basak and A. Pavlova, A model of financialization of commodities, J. Finance, 71 (2016), pp. 1511–1556.
[4] H. Bessembinder, J. F. Coughenour, P. J. Seguin, and M. M. Smoller, Mean reversion in equilibrium asset prices: Evidence from the futures term structure, J. Finance, 50 (1995), pp. 361–375, .
[5] G. Bhardwaj, G. Gorton, and G. Rouwenhorst, Facts and Fantasies about Commodity Futures Ten Years Later, NBER Working Paper 21243, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2015.
[6] Z. Bodie, Commodity futures as a hedge against inflation, J. Portfolio Manag., 9 (1983), pp. 12–17, .
[7] Z. Bodie and V. I. Rosansky, Risk and return in commodity futures, Financ. Anal. J., 36 (1980), pp. 27–39, .
[8] S. Brendle, Portfolio selection under partial observation and filtering, Stochastic Process. Appl., 116 (2006), pp. 701–723. · Zbl 1137.91012
[9] M. Brennan, The role of learning in dynamic portfolio decisions, Eur. Financ. Rev., 1 (1998), pp. 295–306. · Zbl 1029.91511
[10] M. Brennan and Y. Xia, Assessing asset price anomalies, Rev. Financ. Stud., 14 (2001), pp. 905–942.
[11] F. Callier and J. Winkin, Convergence of the time-invariant Riccati differential equation towards its strong solution for stabilizable systems, J. Math. Anal. Appl., 192 (1995), pp. 230–257. · Zbl 0824.93023
[12] J. Casassus and P. Collin-Dufresne, Stochastic convenience yield implied from commodity futures and interest rates, J. Finance, 60 (2005), pp. 2283–2331, .
[13] J. M. Corcuera, P. Imkeller, A. Kohatsu-Higa, and D. Nualart, Additional utility of insiders with imperfect dynamical information, Finance Stoch., 8 (2004), pp. 437–450.
[14] J. Cvitanić, A. Lazrak, L. Martinelli, and F. Zapatero, Dynamic portfolio choice with parameter uncertainty and the economic value of analysts’ recommendations, Rev. Financ. Stud., 19 (2006), pp. 1113–1156.
[15] J. B. Detemple, Asset pricing in a production economy with incomplete information, J. Finance, 41 (1986), pp. 383–391.
[16] U. Dothan and D. Feldman, Equilibrium interest rates and multiperiod bonds in a partially observable economy, J. Finance, 61 (1986), pp. 369–382.
[17] B. Dumas and E. Luciano, An exact solution to a dynamic portfolio choice problem under transactions costs, J. Finance, 46 (1991), pp. 577–595.
[18] C. B. Erb and C. R. Harvey, The strategic and tactical value of commodity futures, Financ. Anal. J., 62 (2006), pp. 69–97, .
[19] G. Genotte, Optimal portfolio choice under incomplete information, J. Finance, 61 (1986), pp. 733–749.
[20] G. Gorton and K. G. Rouwenhorst, Facts and fantasies about commodity futures, Financ. Anal. J., 62 (2006), pp. 47–68, .
[21] S. J. Grossman and Z. Zhou, Optimal investment strategies for controlling drawdowns, Math. Finance, 3 (1993), pp. 241–276. · Zbl 0884.90031
[22] P. Guasoni, Asymmetric information in fads models, Finance Stoch., 10 (2006), pp. 159–177. · Zbl 1101.60047
[23] P. Guasoni and S. Robertson, Portfolio and risk premia for the long run, Ann. Appl. Probab., 22 (2012), pp. 239–284. · Zbl 1247.91172
[24] R. E. Kalman and R. S. Bucy, New results in linear filtering and prediction theory, J. Basic Eng., 83 (1961), pp. 95–108.
[25] I. Karatzas and S. E. Shreve, Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, 2nd ed., Springer-Verlag, New York, 1991. · Zbl 0734.60060
[26] V. Kučera, Algebraic Riccati equation: Hermitian and definite solutions, in The Riccati Equation, Springer, Berlin, 1991, pp. 53–88.
[27] A. Levine, Y. H. Ooi, and M. Richardson, Commodities for the Long Run, NBER Working Paper 22793, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2016, .
[28] H. Markowitz, Portfolio selection, J. Finance, 7 (1952), pp. 77–91, .
[29] R. C. Merton, Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case, Rev. Econom. Statist., 51 (1969), pp. 247–257, .
[30] R. C. Merton, An intertemporal capital asset pricing model, Econometrica, 41 (1973), pp. 867–887.
[31] B. P. Molinari, The stabilizing solution of the algebraic Riccati equation, SIAM J. Control, 11 (1973), pp. 262–271, . · Zbl 0254.34006
[32] I. Pikovsky and I. Karatzas, Anticipative portfolio optimization, Adv. in Appl. Probab., 28 (1996), pp. 1095–1122. · Zbl 0867.90013
[33] D. Struik, A Source Book in Mathematics, 1200-1800, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1986.
[34] K. Zhou, J. Doyle, and K. Glover, Robust and Optimal Control, Prentice–Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ, 1996.
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. It attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming the completeness or perfect precision of the matching.